It can be argued
that the indirect costs are insignificant or even nonexistent, provided
customers and suppliers behave rationally. The expected term of existence may
well be reduced by the decline in the profitability that results in bankruptcy.
Shah and Hijazi (2004) discussed in their paper that if a firm face bankruptcy
then it might begin to face financial distress.
Bankruptcy
occurs when the fixed obligations to creditors cannot be met. In this case,
there is a transfer of ownership and a formal reorganization of the capital
structure of the firm. The cost associated with this transfer can be
categorized as either direct or indirect. Direct costs include legal,
accounting and trustee fees as well as the possible denial of income tax loss
carryovers and carry backs. Indirect costs relate to opportunity costs
resulting from disruptions in firm supplier or firm customer relationships that
are associated with the transfer of ownership or control.
A number of
authors like Baxter (1967), Hirshleifer (1970) have noted that bankruptcy costs
may provide an economic rationale for the existence of a finite, optimal
capital structure, and hence provide reconciliation between the MM theorem and
observed firm behavior. Scott (1976), Kim (1976) has formally introduced
bankruptcy costs in their models. These authors claim that an optimal, finite
debt equity ration can exist, resulting from a tradeoff between the expected
value of bankruptcy costs and the tax savings associated with the deductibility
of interest payments. Essentially, the optimum is reached when the present
value of the government subsidy is just offset by the present value of expected
bankruptcy (Haugen and Senebet 1978).
Haugen and Senebet (1978) worked in their
paper on liquidation of company and compared it with bankruptcy cost, they
concluded that in the presence of rationality and in the absence of systematic
errors in pricing by the capital market, the liquidation decision is best
considered as being independent of the state of the firm or the nature of its
capital structure. It follows that the present value of expected costs
associated with terminating the operations of the firm is also unrelated to the
degree to which the firm employs financial leverage. These costs should not
play a significant role in the determination of an optimal capital structure
and cannot be evoked to reconcile financial theory with capital structures
observed to exist in the real world.
Andrade Gregor and Steven N. Kaplan (1998)
referred to Kaplan and stein (1993am 1993b) that they found that more than 30
percent of management buyout completed after 1985 defaulted later on. Kaplan
and Stein attribute the increased default rates to poorly designed capital and
incentive structures. Andrade Gregor and Steven N. Kaplan (1998) study the
effects and sources of financial distress for thirty one highly leverage
transactions.
The analysis follows each highly leverage transaction to the
resolution of financial distress. They observed that financial economists have
found it difficult to measure the costs of financial distress. The difficulty
is driven by an inability to distinguish whether poor performance by a firm in
financial distress is caused by the financial distress itself or is caused by
the same factors that pushed the firm into financial distress in the first
place. They studied highly leveraged transactions that subsequently become
financially distressed. They estimated the effects of financial distress on
values. From pre transaction to distress resolution, the sample firms
experience a small increase in value.
On the other
hand they estimated the costs of financial distress and their determinants. The
sample firms have positive operating margins at the time of distress that
typically exceed the median industry operating margins. Consistent with some
costs of distress, several firms are forced to curtail capital expenditures and
a number of firms appear to sell assets at depressed prices. They found no
evidence that the distressed firms engage in asset substitution of any kind.
They estimated that net costs of financial distress are 10 to 20 percent of
firm value. At 10 to 20 percent of firm value, our estimates of the net costs
of financial distress suggest that such costs exist and are not trivial in
magnitude.
No comments:
Post a Comment